Tuesday, 30 September 2014 / TRUTH-OUT.ORG

When Economic Prudence Is Seen As Folly

Thursday, 30 May 2013 14:28 By Paul Krugman, Truthout | Report

053013-7(Image: Heng/Lianhe Zaobao - Singapore/CartoonArts International/The New York Times Syndicate)

Combat the epidemic of misinformation that plagues the corporate media! Click here to make a tax-deductible donation to Truthout and keep independent journalism strong.

Nicholas Crafts, an economics professor at the University of Warwick, wrote a really interesting article on the Vox blog recently about Britain's economic policy in the 1930s. The gist is that monetary policy drove recovery through the expectations channel; the Bank of England managed to credibly promise to be irresponsible — that is, to generate inflation.

But how did it do that? Mr. Crafts argues that this was possible for two reasons: the bank was not independent, but just an arm of the Treasury, and the Treasury had a known need to generate some inflation to bring down high debt levels.

This is very closely related to the economist Gauti Eggertsson's analysis of Japanese policy over the same period: there, too, the lack of central bank independence combined with a fiscal imperative made it possible to change monetary expectations in an unorthodox way, which was exactly what was needed (although they should have skipped the invading Manchuria part).

All of this reinforces the important point that — as I put it early in this crisis — we've entered a looking-glass world in which virtue is vice and prudence is folly, and in which doing the responsible thing is a recipe for economic failure.

And it also bodes surprisingly well for Abenomics, which might work in part precisely because of what everyone imagines to be Japan's biggest problem: its huge public debt.

Which Textbook Is That?

Ryan Avent at The Economist, like me, was favorably impressed by Mr. Crafts's article on British policy in the 1930s. I was, however, slightly puzzled, in a tooting-my-own-horn fashion, by the reference — which I missed in Mr. Crafts's article, but was repeated and emphasized by Mr. Avent in an article he wrote on May 13 — to the "textbook approach" of raising inflation expectations to escape a liquidity trap.

Um, which textbook is that, exactly? As far as I know, among basic textbooks only Krugman and Wells even talk about the liquidity trap; certainly Robin Wells and I were the only ones talking about it before 2008. And the whole discussion of inflation expectations and monetary policy in a liquidity trap as a sort of inverted version of the usual credibility problem — in fact, the whole revival of the liquidity trap as a modern concern — dates from a paper I published in 1998: "It's Baaack: Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap."

This isn't purely self-promotion (although obviously that's part of it). I do think that one reason I've done pretty well in tracking this ongoing slump is that I've been thinking about liquidity trap issues for a very long time — years before almost anyone else.

© 2014 The New York Times Company
Truthout has licensed this content. It may not be reproduced by any other source and is not covered by our Creative Commons license.
Paul Krugman joined The New York Times in 1999 as a columnist on the Op-Ed page and continues as a professor of economics and international affairs at Princeton University. He was awarded the Nobel in economic science in 2008. Mr Krugman is the author or editor of 20 books and more than 200 papers in professional journals and edited volumes, including "The Return of Depression Economics" (2008) and "The Conscience of a Liberal" (2007).
Copyright 2014 The New York Times.

Hide Comments

blog comments powered by Disqus
GET DAILY TRUTHOUT UPDATES

FOLLOW togtorsstottofb


When Economic Prudence Is Seen As Folly

Thursday, 30 May 2013 14:28 By Paul Krugman, Truthout | Report

053013-7(Image: Heng/Lianhe Zaobao - Singapore/CartoonArts International/The New York Times Syndicate)

Combat the epidemic of misinformation that plagues the corporate media! Click here to make a tax-deductible donation to Truthout and keep independent journalism strong.

Nicholas Crafts, an economics professor at the University of Warwick, wrote a really interesting article on the Vox blog recently about Britain's economic policy in the 1930s. The gist is that monetary policy drove recovery through the expectations channel; the Bank of England managed to credibly promise to be irresponsible — that is, to generate inflation.

But how did it do that? Mr. Crafts argues that this was possible for two reasons: the bank was not independent, but just an arm of the Treasury, and the Treasury had a known need to generate some inflation to bring down high debt levels.

This is very closely related to the economist Gauti Eggertsson's analysis of Japanese policy over the same period: there, too, the lack of central bank independence combined with a fiscal imperative made it possible to change monetary expectations in an unorthodox way, which was exactly what was needed (although they should have skipped the invading Manchuria part).

All of this reinforces the important point that — as I put it early in this crisis — we've entered a looking-glass world in which virtue is vice and prudence is folly, and in which doing the responsible thing is a recipe for economic failure.

And it also bodes surprisingly well for Abenomics, which might work in part precisely because of what everyone imagines to be Japan's biggest problem: its huge public debt.

Which Textbook Is That?

Ryan Avent at The Economist, like me, was favorably impressed by Mr. Crafts's article on British policy in the 1930s. I was, however, slightly puzzled, in a tooting-my-own-horn fashion, by the reference — which I missed in Mr. Crafts's article, but was repeated and emphasized by Mr. Avent in an article he wrote on May 13 — to the "textbook approach" of raising inflation expectations to escape a liquidity trap.

Um, which textbook is that, exactly? As far as I know, among basic textbooks only Krugman and Wells even talk about the liquidity trap; certainly Robin Wells and I were the only ones talking about it before 2008. And the whole discussion of inflation expectations and monetary policy in a liquidity trap as a sort of inverted version of the usual credibility problem — in fact, the whole revival of the liquidity trap as a modern concern — dates from a paper I published in 1998: "It's Baaack: Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap."

This isn't purely self-promotion (although obviously that's part of it). I do think that one reason I've done pretty well in tracking this ongoing slump is that I've been thinking about liquidity trap issues for a very long time — years before almost anyone else.

© 2014 The New York Times Company
Truthout has licensed this content. It may not be reproduced by any other source and is not covered by our Creative Commons license.
Paul Krugman joined The New York Times in 1999 as a columnist on the Op-Ed page and continues as a professor of economics and international affairs at Princeton University. He was awarded the Nobel in economic science in 2008. Mr Krugman is the author or editor of 20 books and more than 200 papers in professional journals and edited volumes, including "The Return of Depression Economics" (2008) and "The Conscience of a Liberal" (2007).
Copyright 2014 The New York Times.

Hide Comments

blog comments powered by Disqus